article

Drug pricing reforms: the Danish experience

Posted: 20 April 2015 |

Reference price systems for prescription drugs have found widespread use as cost containment tools. Under such regulatory regimes, patients co-pay a fraction of the difference between pharmacy retail price of the drug and a reference price. Reference prices are either externally (based on drug prices in other countries) or internally (based on domestic drug prices) determined.

Drug pricing reforms: the Danish experience

In a recent study, we analysed the effects of a change from external to internal reference pricing in Denmark in 2005, finding that the reform led to substantial reductions in prices, producer revenues, and expenditures for patients and the health insurance system. We also estimated an increase in consumer welfare but the size effect depends on whether or not perceived quality differences between branded and other drugs are taken into account.

To give a brief overview of a few of the factors that shape the Danish healthcare and pharmaceutical markets, Denmark maintains a universal health care system that is financed through general tax revenues. As in many European countries, there are rules on advertising, and doing so for prescription drugs directly to patients is prohibited. However, unlike in many other European countries, in Denmark pharmacists must in the first instance offer the patient the cheapest product within a group of substitutes (mandatory substitution). Patients then decide themselves whether or not to buy that cheapest product or whether to buy a more expensive product.

Meanwhile, product pricing is unregulated in Denmark. Sellers must notify the governmental body, the Danish Medicines Agency, of pharmacy wholesale prices. The agency updates prices every 14 days and makes them publicly available online. It also ensures that prices are identical nationwide and classifies products into substitution groups based on active substance, administration form, strength, and package size.

Reference pricing in Denmark

Governments and regulators around the world are facing increasing costs of medical treatments driven by a steadily growing life expectancy, aging populations, and often broad public health insurance coverage. In an attempt to reduce the expenditure growth, various cost containment tools have been introduced. Among those tools, restricting patients’ reimbursements using drug-specific reference prices appears to be a particularly widely-embraced approach. Reference pricing makes patients more price-conscious as their out-of-pocket payment – the co-payment – increases in the retail price of the drug chosen.

Patient co-payments are determined as the pharmacy retail price minus the reimbursement, which in turn constitutes a fraction of a drug’s reference price. Reference prices are either functions (often the average or minimum) of prices of substitute products in other countries or a function of prices of domestic substitutes. While the former is referred to as an ‘external’ reference price, the latter is termed an ‘internal’ reference price. While it is well documented that reference pricing leads to reduced prices for drugs, much less is known about the design of such systems. To overcome this research gap, we studied the switch from external to internal reference pricing in Denmark that took place in April 2005 (documented in our recent paper [Kaiser et al. 2014]). Denmark used to base reference prices on the European average price of substitute products before the reference pricing reform and has based it on the price of the cheapest domestic substitute since the reform.

There are several reasons why we would expect the switch from internal to external reference pricing to strengthen competition and to reduce prices. Firstly, firms now faced demand that was more price-elastic above the external reference price than below it, prior to the reform, introducing a tendency for prices to cluster at the reference price. Since Danish prices were comparatively low in Europe, this kept the Danish price level up. Secondly, since the reform, Danish patients have had to pay the full difference between the retail price and the reference price ‘out-of-pocket’ when buying a product that is not the least expensive one. This makes patients more price-sensitive and leads to tougher competition among firms in the market.

Our analysis focuses on cholesterol-lowering drugs statins. To estimate the reform’s effects on price, demand and economic welfare we would ideally observe the market for statins simultaneously with both internal and external reference pricing. Given that we can only observe the market either with one or the other at any one time, the empirical challenge we face is how best to construct an artificial, ‘counter-factual’ world in which the reform had taken place in the pre-reform period already. The empirical questions we specifically ask are, (i) how high would list prices have been had the reform taken place pre-reform, and (ii) how would demand have adjusted to a change in co-payments? By constructing such a counter-factual world, we can filter out factors other than the reform that may have affected post-reform market outcomes. The details about the methodology we employ are given in Kaiser et al (2014).

A mixed bag

The key finding of our analysis is that the reference price reform has substantially different effects on producer revenues, government expenditures and patients’ co-payments. Our estimated price decreases are most substantial for generics where list prices decline by 44%, while retail prices for branded drugs change comparatively little. Even though we estimate a decrease in patient co-payments on average, they increase for branded drugs. This is the case since reference prices for branded drugs decrease relatively more than list prices.

These changes in absolute and relative price terms have large effects on the demand for statins. Overall demand for statins increases by 13%. Growth in demand is strongest for generic drugs where it increases by 20%. Parallel imported drugs witness a demand increase of 62%, up from a pre-reform market share of 13%. Demand for branded drugs declines by 21%. Combining price and demand effects, we estimate overall decreases in reimbursements and consumer expenditures of around 10%.

Turning to the effects of the reform on firms, we find that parallel importers benefit most from the reform. Their overall revenues increase by 42%, while the revenues of firms selling generic and branded drugs increase by 20% and decrease by 29%, respectively. Overall, producer revenues decrease by 10%.

Finally, we calculate consumer welfare under two polar assumptions: (i) any consumer preference for branded drugs is ‘real’ and should be included in the calculation of consumer surplus and (ii) any preference for branded drugs is ‘artificial’, for example, based on an unsubstantiated belief that branded drugs have superior therapeutic effects, and should not be included in consumer surplus. Our estimations reveal that consumers prefer branded drugs over parallel imports and generics. If we treat the perceived quality differences between these different types of drugs as real, the increase in consumer surplus is lower because consumers substitute away from branded drugs (for which they have a preference) to generic drugs. Hence, we estimate a modest reform-induced increase in consumer surplus of 7% under this assumption. Estimated consumer welfare is much higher if we treat the perceived quality differences as artificial, resulting in an increase in consumer surplus of 36% due to the reform. 

Conclusion

Despite the specific features of the regulatory setup, we believe that the Danish experience provides some general insights into the optimal design of reference price systems. Under the internal reference pricing regime adopted in Denmark, patients always pay the full price difference between the drug bought and the cheapest substitute. This makes patients more sensitive to relative prices and strengthens competition. Also, policy makers do not have to find ways of setting reference prices close to the competitive level in order to mimic a competitive market. This constitutes an important advantage over external reference price systems that often effectively turn the reference price into the market price.

There is no doubt that reference pricing must be complemented with other rules and regulations for generic competition to work well. In that vein, we believe that mandatory substitution spurred generic competition and helped realise the gains from the switch from external to internal reference pricing.

Reference

Kaiser, U., S.J. Mendez, T. Rønde, H. Ullrich (2014): Regulation of pharmaceutical prices: Evidence from a reference price reform in Denmark. Journal of Health Economics 36, p. 174-187.

Biographies

Ulrich Kaiser is a chaired professor of Entrepreneurship at University of Zurich (Switzerland) and holds a part-time position at Copenhagen Business School (Denmark). His research focuses on empirical analysis of innovation, regulation and business strategy. He studied economics at University of Konstanz (Germany) where he also gained his PhD. He is presently affiliated with Centre for European Economic Research (Mannheim, Germany) and Institute for the Study of Labor (Bonn, Germany).

Susan Mendez is a Research Fellow at Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research (Australia). Before joining the Institute, Susan was a Research Associate at University of Zurich (Switzerland) from where she also has her PhD. Her research interests are applied industrial organisation, applied microeconomics, health economics, and labour economics.

Thomas Rønde holds a professorship in innovation and entrepreneurship at Copenhagen Business School (Denmark). He did his PhD in economics at University Pompeu Fabra (Barcelona, Spain).  His primary research interests are innovation, health economics, regulation, and competition policy. He is affiliated with Centre for Economic Policy Research (London, UK) and serves as Chief Economist at the Danish Competition and Consumer Authority.

Hannes Ullrich is a senior research associate at DIW Berlin (Germany) and University of Zurich (Switzerland). His research focuses on empirical analysis of product market competition and regulation with an emphasis on the pharmaceutical industry. He studied economics at University of Mannheim (Germany) and Toulouse School of Economics (France) and completed his PhD in economics at University of Zurich.